英語(yǔ)閱讀 學(xué)英語(yǔ),練聽(tīng)力,上聽(tīng)力課堂! 注冊(cè) 登錄
> 輕松閱讀 > 雙語(yǔ)閱讀 >  內(nèi)容

俄國(guó)十月革命的三點(diǎn)教訓(xùn)

所屬教程:雙語(yǔ)閱讀

瀏覽:

2017年12月14日

手機(jī)版
掃描二維碼方便學(xué)習(xí)和分享
It remains one of the greatest experiments in economic and political history. A bloody civil war, the abolition of private property, the creation of a command economy with near full state ownership, price regulation and the elimination of markets.

它仍是經(jīng)濟(jì)和政治史上最偉大的實(shí)驗(yàn)之一。一場(chǎng)血腥的內(nèi)戰(zhàn),廢除私有制,建立幾乎完全是國(guó)有的計(jì)劃經(jīng)濟(jì),實(shí)行價(jià)格管制,取締市場(chǎng)。

One hundred years on from the Russian Revolution, three main lessons emerge from the 75-year Great Soviet Experiment. They are not rocket science but worth re-stating. First, industrialisation through terror is inefficient. Second, without terror the command economy eventually flags and goes bankrupt. Third, lack of political competition creates a rigid governance system unable to make necessary reforms.

俄國(guó)革命已過(guò)去100年,這場(chǎng)75年的“蘇維埃大實(shí)驗(yàn)”告訴了我們3條主要教訓(xùn)。它們并非尖端科學(xué),但值得重新述說(shuō)。首先,通過(guò)恐怖統(tǒng)治實(shí)現(xiàn)工業(yè)化是低效的。其次,如果沒(méi)有恐怖統(tǒng)治,計(jì)劃經(jīng)濟(jì)將最終萎靡并破產(chǎn)。第三,缺乏政治競(jìng)爭(zhēng)造成了僵化的治理體系,無(wú)法實(shí)行必要的改革。

The first is probably the least obvious. Stalin accomplished industrialisation and eventually led the Soviet Union to victory in the second world war. His method was top-down and, in the words of the writers Daron Acemoglu and James Robinson, “brutal but effective”.

第一個(gè)可能是最不明顯的。斯大林(Stalin)實(shí)現(xiàn)了工業(yè)化,并最終領(lǐng)導(dǎo)蘇聯(lián)在二戰(zhàn)中獲勝。他的方法是自上而下的,用作家達(dá)龍•阿杰姆奧盧(Daron Acemoglu)和詹姆斯•羅賓遜(James Robinson)的話來(lái)說(shuō),“殘酷但有效”。

The benefit of centralised economic control is that it allows you to move 25-30 per cent of the labour force from farm to factory within just one decade. However, a recent study I co-authored found this did not work as planned: the gains from moving resources to industry did not make up for destroying productivity within both agriculture and industry. Terror is brutal and effective in moving resources, but it is not productive in organising them efficiently.

中央控制經(jīng)濟(jì)的好處在于它讓蘇聯(lián)得以在僅僅10年的時(shí)間內(nèi)就讓25%至30%的勞動(dòng)力從農(nóng)場(chǎng)轉(zhuǎn)移到工廠。然而,最近我作為聯(lián)合作者所做的一項(xiàng)研究發(fā)現(xiàn),其效果沒(méi)有達(dá)到計(jì)劃:將資源轉(zhuǎn)向工業(yè)的好處沒(méi)有彌補(bǔ)農(nóng)業(yè)和工業(yè)生產(chǎn)率都遭到破壞的影響。在轉(zhuǎn)移資源方面,恐怖統(tǒng)治是殘酷但有效的,但在高效組織資源方面它成果低下。

The net economic benefits of Stalin’s policies were trivial — and this is not to mention millions who perished due to repression and famine. Also, the Soviet Union could not win the war alone — resources and equipment provided by the US were essential in beating Hitler.

斯大林政策給經(jīng)濟(jì)帶來(lái)的凈好處微乎其微,這還不包括數(shù)百萬(wàn)人因?yàn)楸绘?zhèn)壓和饑餓而死。另外,蘇聯(lián)是不可能依靠自己贏得戰(zhàn)爭(zhēng)勝利的,美國(guó)提供的資源和裝備在擊敗希特勒(Hitler)方面起到了關(guān)鍵作用。

After the war, the Soviet economy recovered, Sputnik was launched and nuclear parity with the US maintained. Yet, it failed to deliver growth and innovation — proving that competitive markets are needed for efficient incentives. Also, as shown by the economist János Kornai, a collectivised system is inherently vulnerable to “soft budget constraints”. In a socialist economy, all inefficient enterprises are bailed out by the state — hence managers have no incentives to avoid bankruptcy.

二戰(zhàn)后,蘇聯(lián)經(jīng)濟(jì)復(fù)蘇,發(fā)射了斯普特尼克號(hào)(Sputnik)衛(wèi)星,并在核領(lǐng)域與美國(guó)保持了勢(shì)均力敵。然而,蘇聯(lián)未能實(shí)現(xiàn)經(jīng)濟(jì)增長(zhǎng)和創(chuàng)新,這證明,有效激勵(lì)需要競(jìng)爭(zhēng)性市場(chǎng)。另外,就像經(jīng)濟(jì)學(xué)家雅諾什•科爾奈(János Kornai)所說(shuō)的,集體制從本質(zhì)上來(lái)說(shuō)在“軟性預(yù)算約束”下很脆弱。在社會(huì)主義經(jīng)濟(jì)中,所有低效的企業(yè)都會(huì)由政府紓困,因此管理者沒(méi)有避免破產(chǎn)的激勵(lì)。

Soft budget constraints also feature in market economies — as the massive bailouts since the financial crisis show. But there is a major difference: if a capitalist firm goes bankrupt, private shareholders lose their equity. If a socialist one cannot pay its debts they are taken over by the state — and eventually the whole state goes bankrupt. When Mr Kornai was writing in the late 1970s it was unthinkable that a superpower like the Soviet Union could go bankrupt. In fact its bankruptcy was not just plausible — it turned out to be inevitable.

“軟性預(yù)算約束”也出現(xiàn)在市場(chǎng)經(jīng)濟(jì)中,就像金融危機(jī)之后出現(xiàn)的大規(guī)模紓困所顯示的那樣。但其中存在一個(gè)巨大區(qū)別:如果資本主義企業(yè)破產(chǎn),私人股東會(huì)血本無(wú)歸。如果社會(huì)主義企業(yè)無(wú)法償還債務(wù),政府可以為其買單,最終整個(gè)國(guó)家破產(chǎn)。在科爾奈在上世紀(jì)70年代末撰文時(shí),人們難以想象蘇聯(lián)這種超級(jí)大國(guó)會(huì)破產(chǎn)。實(shí)際上,蘇聯(lián)的破產(chǎn)不僅是合理的,而且事實(shí)證明是不可避免的。

With the end of Stalinist terror the government could no longer resist pressures to raise living standards. To pay for this, Moscow resorted to petrodollars and later loans. By the late 1980s the Soviet budget deficit went into double-digit percentages of gross domestic product. In its last year it was 30 per cent of GDP. Creditors stopped lending and the Soviet Union was no more.

隨著斯大林式的恐怖統(tǒng)治結(jié)束,蘇聯(lián)政府無(wú)法再抵抗提高生活水平的壓力。要為此買單,蘇聯(lián)政府求助于石油美元以及后來(lái)的貸款。到上世紀(jì)80年代末,蘇聯(lián)的預(yù)算赤字與國(guó)內(nèi)生產(chǎn)總值(GDP)之比達(dá)到兩位數(shù)。在蘇聯(lián)解體前的最后一年,這個(gè)比例達(dá)到30%。債權(quán)人停止貸款,蘇聯(lián)不復(fù)存在。

As bankruptcy loomed, why were Soviet leaders unable to recognise the problem and launch radical reforms? The answer points to the third, most painful lesson. In the absence of political competition and free debate, the USSR ended up with a leadership that was neither competent nor decisive. This was not a coincidence — it was how that system selected and promoted its leaders.

在破產(chǎn)逼近之際,蘇聯(lián)領(lǐng)導(dǎo)人為何無(wú)法意識(shí)到這個(gè)問(wèn)題并推行徹底的改革呢?答案指向第三個(gè)也是最痛苦的教訓(xùn)。在缺乏政治競(jìng)爭(zhēng)和自由辯論的情況下,蘇聯(lián)的領(lǐng)導(dǎo)層最后既無(wú)能又無(wú)決斷。這并非巧合,它是這個(gè)體制遴選和提拔領(lǐng)導(dǎo)人的方式造成的。

The Great Soviet Experiment demonstrated the deficiencies and unsustainability of the non-market model. Yet still every now and then proposals emerge for a new version of socialism — from “Bolivarian” to market varieties, from state capitalism to a new “digital Gosplan” matching algorithms to economic planning. In decades of socialist experimenting, communists tried many alternatives to the market. None of them worked. That is what we should remember 100 years later.

“蘇維埃大實(shí)驗(yàn)”顯示了非市場(chǎng)模式的缺陷和不可持續(xù)。然而,時(shí)常會(huì)出現(xiàn)社會(huì)主義新版本的提議,從“玻利瓦爾主義”(Bolivarianism)到各種市場(chǎng)經(jīng)濟(jì)變體,從國(guó)家資本主義到把算法與經(jīng)濟(jì)規(guī)劃匹配的新的“數(shù)字國(guó)家計(jì)劃委員會(huì)”(digital Gosplan)。在幾十年的社會(huì)主義實(shí)驗(yàn)中,共產(chǎn)主義者嘗試了很多替代市場(chǎng)的方案。其中沒(méi)有一個(gè)成功。這就是我們?cè)?00年后應(yīng)該記住的事情。

The writer is chief economist, European Bank for Reconstruction and Development

本文作者是歐洲復(fù)興開(kāi)發(fā)銀行(European Bank for Reconstruction and Development)首席經(jīng)濟(jì)學(xué)家
 


用戶搜索

瘋狂英語(yǔ) 英語(yǔ)語(yǔ)法 新概念英語(yǔ) 走遍美國(guó) 四級(jí)聽(tīng)力 英語(yǔ)音標(biāo) 英語(yǔ)入門 發(fā)音 美語(yǔ) 四級(jí) 新東方 七年級(jí) 賴世雄 zero是什么意思臺(tái)州市浦山家園英語(yǔ)學(xué)習(xí)交流群

網(wǎng)站推薦

英語(yǔ)翻譯英語(yǔ)應(yīng)急口語(yǔ)8000句聽(tīng)歌學(xué)英語(yǔ)英語(yǔ)學(xué)習(xí)方法

  • 頻道推薦
  • |
  • 全站推薦
  • 推薦下載
  • 網(wǎng)站推薦